個(gè)人對(duì)個(gè)人(P2P)市場(chǎng)曾經(jīng)很簡(jiǎn)單:最初只有一個(gè)eBay,。如果你想賣(mài)掉一支壞了的激光筆,,在eBay能找到買(mǎi)家。接下來(lái)有了本地交易網(wǎng)站Craigslist,,不久之后,,P2P平臺(tái)把所有你能想到的市場(chǎng)中的買(mǎi)賣(mài)雙方都聯(lián)系在了一起:手工藝品(Etsy);零工(TaskRabbit),;交通(Uber),;住宿(Airbnb);消費(fèi)貸款(Zopa),;甚至酒類(lèi)(Drizly),。
當(dāng)你意識(shí)到自己真的能在周六晚上的舊金山坐車(chē)回家,、或是出租閣樓賺些錢(qián)時(shí),你會(huì)興奮一段時(shí)間,,但是反對(duì)情緒一直在發(fā)酵,,其中夾雜著兩層抱怨,,在一年前亞特蘭大出租車(chē)公司和司機(jī)起訴Uber一案中被很好地展現(xiàn)了出來(lái),。
“Uber在亞特蘭大的運(yùn)營(yíng)幾乎毫不考慮乘客的安全問(wèn)題,也從未顧及保護(hù)乘客的法律,,”一名原告在《亞特蘭大憲法日?qǐng)?bào)》(Atlanta Journal-Constitution)上發(fā)表聲明稱(chēng),,“自Uber開(kāi)始運(yùn)營(yíng)以來(lái),我們的收入節(jié)節(jié)下滑,,擁有合法執(zhí)照的出租車(chē)司機(jī)正在離開(kāi)這個(gè)行業(yè),。”
換句話說(shuō),Uber等P2P服務(wù)被稱(chēng)為危險(xiǎn)服務(wù),,而且給現(xiàn)有從業(yè)者帶來(lái)了不受歡迎的競(jìng)爭(zhēng),。(一些研究支持這個(gè)常識(shí)性結(jié)論:新競(jìng)爭(zhēng)者威脅到了現(xiàn)有從業(yè)者的收入。)
這兩點(diǎn)或許貌似截然不同的問(wèn)題,。你在Airbnb上出租一個(gè)單間時(shí)擔(dān)心消防通道指示是一回事,,而保護(hù)當(dāng)?shù)卣?guī)酒店經(jīng)營(yíng)者的利潤(rùn)空間是另外一回事。
不過(guò),,這兩個(gè)問(wèn)題不可避免地被攪在一起,,因?yàn)樗鼈兌加|及了現(xiàn)有從業(yè)者受到監(jiān)管的方式。人們希望監(jiān)管機(jī)構(gòu)通過(guò)讓醉酒者和性侵者難以當(dāng)專(zhuān)車(chē)司機(jī),、易失火建筑不能接待毫無(wú)戒心的游客,、以及雇主無(wú)法剝削工人,來(lái)保護(hù)消費(fèi)者,、雇員以及公眾的利益,。但是,一些法規(guī)似乎更傾向于保護(hù)局內(nèi)人,,而不是消費(fèi)者,。
想想紐約出租車(chē)牌照制度:在沒(méi)有牌照的情況下你不能開(kāi)出租車(chē),出租車(chē)牌照不時(shí)成為數(shù)百萬(wàn)美元的資產(chǎn),,往往歸投資者所有,,由其以每天100美元或更高的價(jià)格把牌照租給司機(jī)。菜鳥(niǎo)Uber和Lyft不止?fàn)帄Z乘客,,它們還爭(zhēng)搶司機(jī),。相比向牌照所有者交份兒錢(qián),司機(jī)或許更傾向于把傭金交給這些新老板,。
出租車(chē)牌照成為稀缺資產(chǎn),,純粹是由監(jiān)管者的一紙文書(shū)造成的,。在這種情況下,即使不是狂熱的自由主義者,,你也能看出監(jiān)管者的動(dòng)機(jī)是保護(hù)這些資產(chǎn)的價(jià)值,。再說(shuō),不只是自由市場(chǎng)原教旨主義者才會(huì)相信:如果消費(fèi)者認(rèn)為出租車(chē)提供的服務(wù)更安全,,他們會(huì)花錢(qián)購(gòu)買(mǎi)更安全的服務(wù),。
這或許有助于從不同角度來(lái)探究這場(chǎng)辯論。這些新競(jìng)爭(zhēng)者是否提供了有價(jià)值的新服務(wù),,還是只是利用技術(shù)規(guī)避了其他人必須支付的稅款以此套利,、從其他競(jìng)爭(zhēng)者必須跳過(guò)去的監(jiān)管障礙下面鉆了過(guò)去?
如果它們有實(shí)實(shí)在在的經(jīng)濟(jì)價(jià)值,,那么就該由監(jiān)管者琢磨出如何釋放價(jià)值,,而不是試圖通過(guò)立法去消滅它。
麗蘭褠納夫(Liran Einav),、基婭拉法羅納托(Chiara Farronato)和喬納森萊文(Jonathan Levin) 3位經(jīng)濟(jì)學(xué)家對(duì)P2P市場(chǎng)進(jìn)行的新研究發(fā)現(xiàn),,其經(jīng)濟(jì)價(jià)值確實(shí)存在。P2P市場(chǎng)讓兩件過(guò)去難以想象的事情成為可能,。
第一,,它令貧瘠的市場(chǎng)變得富饒而肥沃。eBay就是一個(gè)典型的例子,,它使得離奇產(chǎn)品的買(mǎi)賣(mài)雙方找到彼此并從交易中受益,。Etsy和eBay的模式一樣,你可以在這里找到出售像肢解的青蛙一樣的毛絨玩具(似乎不太可能在商業(yè)街找到立足之地的產(chǎn)品)的賣(mài)家,。
P2P第二個(gè)妙招是將兼職者引入該市場(chǎng)以滿(mǎn)足需求激增時(shí)的情況,。只是為了應(yīng)對(duì)暑假旺季就建設(shè)新酒店,或是為了解決新年夜的打車(chē)高峰而增加出租車(chē)——那是效率低下的,;但是,,只要有需求,P2P市場(chǎng)就可以引入一些額外的供應(yīng),。結(jié)果就是,,周五晚上11點(diǎn)在P2P平臺(tái)更容易叫到車(chē),學(xué)校假期時(shí)P2P提供的客房?jī)r(jià)格更合理,。
P2P市場(chǎng)非常值得擁有,。因此,監(jiān)管者面臨的挑戰(zhàn)是趕上其發(fā)展的腳步,。應(yīng)該如何把Airbnb上每年只把房間出租10晚的房東與長(zhǎng)期經(jīng)營(yíng)住宿加早餐旅店(B&B)的房東放在同一個(gè)監(jiān)管層面上,?Uber專(zhuān)車(chē)司機(jī)是公司雇員(就像加州勞工委員會(huì)最近裁決的那樣),還是利用Uber軟件工作的自由職業(yè)者(像Uber主張的那樣),?或是其他性質(zhì),?
詹姆斯蘇洛維爾奇(James Surowiecki)最近在《紐約客》(New Yorker)的專(zhuān)欄認(rèn)為是這屬于“其他性質(zhì)”,,呼吁進(jìn)行監(jiān)管改革給“零工經(jīng)濟(jì)的工作者提供一個(gè)更好地兼顧靈活性和安全性的辦法”。這聽(tīng)起來(lái)像是一個(gè)令人向往的目標(biāo),,盡管實(shí)現(xiàn)它并沒(méi)有那么簡(jiǎn)單,。為Uber司機(jī)或是TaskRabbit的“任務(wù)方”提供養(yǎng)老金、帶薪休假或是失業(yè)保險(xiǎn),,將需要明智的法規(guī)和明智的管理體系,。
P2P市場(chǎng)或許曾經(jīng)很簡(jiǎn)單;但如今它關(guān)系到的遠(yuǎn)遠(yuǎn)不只是偶爾有一支壞掉的激光筆,。(中國(guó)進(jìn)出口網(wǎng))
Peer-to-peer markets used to be simple: there was eBay. If you had a broken laser pointer you wanted to sell, eBay was the place to find a buyer. Then came the local marketplace Craigslist and, before long, peer-to-peer markets were linking buyers and sellers in every market imaginable: crafts (Etsy); chores (TaskRabbit); transport (Uber); accommodation (Airbnb); consumer loans (Zopa); and even booze (Drizly).
It was exciting, for a while, to realise that you could actually get a car home on a Saturday night in San Francisco, or make money renting out your attic, but the backlash has been simmering for some time. That backlash mixes two complaints, elegantly exemplified when a group of taxicab owners and drivers sued Uber in Atlanta a year ago.
“Uber has been operating in Atlanta with little concern about the safety of their passengers and zero concern for the laws that protect them,” said one of the plaintiffs in a statement to The Atlanta Journal-Constitution. “Our incomes have steadily dropped since Uber started and legally licensed drivers are leaving the business.”
In other words, peer-to-peer services such as Uber are said to be hazardous, and they are also unwelcome competition for incumbents. (Several studies have supported the common-sense conclusion that these new competitors threaten the revenue of existing players.)
These might seem very different issues. It’s one thing to worry about signposting fire exits when you let out a spare room on Airbnb. Protecting the profit margins of fine upstanding local hoteliers is another matter.
Yet the two questions are inevitably tangled up, because both touch on the way incumbents are regulated. One would hope that regulators protect consumers, employees and the public by making it more difficult for drunks and sexual predators to drive cars, for firetraps to host unsuspecting tourists, and for employers to exploit workers. But some regulations seem designed more to protect insiders than to protect consumers.
Consider the New York taxi medallion system: you can’t drive a taxicab without one, and they’ve been million-dollar assets at times, often owned by investors and leased to drivers at a rate of $100 or more a day. New kids Uber and Lyft not only compete for passengers, they compete for drivers too, who may prefer to pay commission to these new players than the flat fee to the medallion owner.
Taxi medallions are a scarce asset created purely by a stroke of the regulator’s pen, and you don’t need to be a hardcore libertarian to conclude that, in this case, the regulator is motivated by protecting the value of this asset. Nor does it take a free-market fundamentalist to believe that if consumers think that taxicabs provide a safer service, they will pay for that safer service.
It may help to approach the debate from a different direction. Are these new players providing a valuable new service or are they merely an arbitrage play, using technology to sidestep taxes that others must pay, and to limbo-dance under regulatory hurdles that rivals must jump?
If the economic value is real, then it is up to the regulators to figure out how to unleash that value rather than trying to legislate it out of existence.
A new study of peer-to-peer markets by economists Liran Einav, Chiara Farronato and Jonathan Levin argues that the economic value is there all right. Peer-to-peer markets make two things possible that were previously hard to imagine.
The first is to make arid markets lush and fertile. The quintessential example is eBay, enabling buyers and sellers of the quirkiest products to find each other and gain by trading. Etsy fits the eBay mould, with sellers who will knit you a cuddly toy designed to resemble a dissected frog, a product that seems unlikely to find a niche on the high street.
The second peer-to-peer trick is to introduce part-timers into the market to meet surges in demand. It’s inefficient to build hotels just to cope with the summer rush, or taxis to cope with New Year’s Eve but, if the demand is there, peer-to-peer markets can pull in a bit of extra supply. As a result, it should be easier to get a cab at 11pm on a Friday, and prices for hotel rooms should be more reasonable during school holidays.
Peer-to-peer markets are well worth havin. The challenge for regulators, then, is to catch up. How should Airbnb landlords who let a room for 10 nights a year be placed on a level playing field with regular bed-and-breakfast landlords? Are Uber drivers employees (as a California labour commissioner recently ruled)? Or freelancers using Uber’s software to help them do their jobs (as Uber insists)? Or something else?
James Surowiecki, writing in The New Yorker, recently argued for “something else”, and called for a regulatory overhaul to give “gig-economy workers a better balance of flexibility and security”. That sounds like an admirable aim, although achieving it isn’t straightforward. Giving pensions, vacation rights or unemployment insurance to Uber drivers or TaskRabbit “taskers” would require both clever rules and clever admin systems.
Peer-to-peer markets may once have been simple; now there is more at stake than the occasional broken laser pointer.